In financial economics, a state-price security, also called an Arrow–Debreu security, a pure security, or a primitive security is a contract that agrees to pay one unit of a numeraire if a particular state occurs at a particular time in the future and pays zero numeraire in all the other states. The price of this security is the state price of this particular state of the world. The state price vector is the vector of state prices for all states. As such, any derivatives contract whose settlement value is a function of an underlying asset whose value is uncertain at contract date can be decomposed as a linear combination of its Arrow–Debreu securities, and thus as a weighted sum of its state prices. The Arrow–Debreu model is the central model in general equilibrium theory and uses state prices in the process of proving the existence of a unique general equilibrium.
Example
Imagine a world where two states are possible tomorrow: peace and war. Denote the random variable which represents the state as ω; denote tomorrow's random variable as ω1. Thus, ω1 can take two values: ω1=P and ω1=W. Let's imagine that:
There is a security that pays off £1 if tomorrow's state is "P" and nothing if the state is "W". The price of this security is qP
There is a security that pays off £1 if tomorrow's state is "W" and nothing if the state is "P". The price of this security is qW
The prices qP and qW are the state prices. The factors that affect these state prices are:
"Time preferences for consumption and the productivity of capital". That is to say that the time value of money affects the state prices.
The probabilities of ω1=P and ω1=W. The more likely a move to W is, the higher the price qWgets, since qW insures the agent against the occurrence of state W. The seller of this insurance would demand a higher premium.
The preferences of the agent. Suppose the agent has a standard concaveutility function which depends on the state of the world. Assume that the agent loses an equal amount if the state is "W" as he would gain if the state was "P". Now, even if you assume that the above-mentioned probabilities ω1=P and ω1=W are equal, the changes in utility for the agent are not: Due to his decreasing marginal utility, the utility gain from a "peace dividend" tomorrow would be lower than the utility lost from the "war" state. If our agent were rational, he would pay more to insure against the down state than his net gain from the up state would be.
If the agent buys both qP and qW, he has secured £1 for tomorrow. He has purchased a riskless bond. The price of the bond is b0 = qP + qW. Now consider a security with state-dependent payouts. The price of this security is c0 = qPcP + qWcW. Generally, the usefulness of state prices arises from their linearity: Any security can be valued as the sum over all possible states of state price times payoff in that state: Analogously, for a continuous random variable indicating a continuum of possible states, the value is found by integrating over the state price density.